Search the Site

Episode Transcript

My guest today, Robert Solow, is an absolute giant in the field of economics. He received the Nobel Prize in 1987 for his pioneering work on the topic of economic growth.

SOLOW: When I first got interested in economic questions, the whole point was that the system appeared to be broken and it was necessary to find ways to patch it together.

Welcome to People I (Mostly) Admire, with Steve Levitt.

But Robert Solow is more than just a great researcher. He was one of the most inspiring teachers I ever had, and he’s been a legendary mentor to generations of students at MIT, four of whom have themselves gone on to win Nobel Prizes. And at the age of 98, still as sharp as ever, he’s a model for growing old gracefully.

*      *      *

LEVITT: So you taught me macroeconomics almost 30 years ago. You know I’m no macroeconomist, but your class was the best class that I took at M.I.T. I remember, I would read these macro papers ahead of class. I mean, I would spend hours and I would understand nothing about the paper. It was pure math to me, math I didn’t understand. And then you would roll into class and you would describe these papers in the simplest terms. You would strip away all the math and you would show what was going on with a few words, with a few equations. And  I really stood in awe of you being able to do that.

SOLOW: That’s the only way I can understand anything, is to break it down into simplicities. And I’m glad you liked it.

LEVITT: Not only I liked it, but that is actually something that I carried with me. You gave me the belief that no matter how complex an author or a creator says something is, that deep down it’s really simple. You just have to find the simplicity.

SOLOW: You have to find the basic thing that’s happening. God may understand the rest of it, but it’s not given to us to do that. All we can do is figure out — you punch it here, it reacts there. Why? There’s some chain of connections that’s going on. And by the way, there’s an element of illusion there, Steve. If I couldn’t do that, I wouldn’t try teaching it.

LEVITT: So you’ve spent a good part of your career studying economic growth and to economists, economic growth is one of the most fundamental measures of an economy’s health. But it seems more and more, driven heavily by climate change, there’s a rising chorus of voices arguing that economic growth shouldn’t be an objective, even that economic growth is the enemy. What do you think of those arguments?

SOLOW: First of all, the fact that I’ve spent much of my life studying the way growth occurs in modern industrial capitalist economies does not mean I’m an enthusiast for it. I could have spent my life studying the bacteria that caused tuberculosis. That doesn’t mean I’m in favor of them, so I perfectly agree. I do not think that growth itself is or should be a particular objective for a modern economy. There are, however, a lot of people, in the profession and outside the profession, who think that a modern, industrial, capitalist economy cannot exist without growing. And I would like to start by talking about that question, okay?

LEVITT: Great.

SOLOW: So, I want to imagine an economy like ours and think about what it would be like if it were stationary, if it were not growing and not shrinking, but just fixed at whatever size we’re talking about. The first thing that would have to be true is that the population is constant. Now, I want to make another assumption, imagine that there’s no innovation going on. There are no new products, no new industries, nothing like that. The economy is just stationary. It just repeats itself. Okay.

LEVITT: Okay.

SOLOW: I think the important thing to realize is that there is no law of economics, no principles of economics, that say that such an economy could not exist and be healthy. It’s not written anywhere that for a capitalist economy, it’s grow or die. That’s just not true. The one glitch that could occur in this stationary state is that the population wants to increase its wealth by saving, even though the economy is stationary, but we can’t let that saving get into investment because if the saving goes into building new factories, building new buildings, whatever, that moves us out of the stationary state into growth. But there’s an easy solution to that: the government satisfies the public’s wish to accumulate by running a deficit and selling them bonds and using the proceeds not to build new roads, or build new anything, but to put on beautiful fireworks displays, wonderful concerts, maybe annual dramatic festivals like the ancient Athenians. That situation could simply go on forever. Now I come to the rub that I don’t think most people think about: this non-growing economy has, as I said, no new industries, no new products, nothing like that. That can’t be good for social mobility. What I’m afraid of is that in such an economy, the same good jobs and high status occupations would repeat themselves year after year. And the people who have those jobs would groom their children to follow in their footsteps. And that kind of society would tend to be a hereditary oligarchy. And that’s not good. So if I were trying to bring about — for the sake of warding off climate change, for the sake of preserving the environment — a non-growth economy, what I would be thinking about is how you provide for social mobility, how you provide for the children of relatively poor parents to become relatively better off while some of the children of relatively well-off parents fall in the income distribution. That’s the hard part. There’s nothing in my background to make me a specialist in how to do that, but I can see that it would be a really serious problem. But it’s not a narrowly economic problem. It’s a matter of organizing the society. If you didn’t let the children of Yale graduates go to Yale, that would help. But in fact, everything we know about life says that Yale will make it easy for the children of Yale graduates to go to Yale. Now, in a nutshell, that’s my attitude toward — that’s a hell of a big nutshell. But that’s what I think about that question.

LEVITT: I’m surprised by your answer because I thought you would say, “Well, there are two ways for an economy to grow. One way is to use more inputs, to use more capital and more labor, and the other is to use the existing inputs more efficiently.” And I thought you’d say, “Historically, most of our growth comes from using inputs more efficiently. And nobody should worry about using inputs more efficiently. That’s just great. Even if you are afraid of climate change, what could be better than using inputs more efficiently?” What’s wrong with that answer?

SOLOW: That’s perfectly compatible with what I’ve been saying. I’m for using all the natural resources that we can efficiently, but when you use up a natural resource, you use up a natural resource. When I tried to draw this picture of a stationary economy — you know, this is an idea that goes back to John Stuart Mill — that economy can be run efficiently or inefficiently. And I’m for efficiency, which does not imply growth. It simply implies a higher level than an inefficient economy. I’m for the efficient economy, provided the efficiency we’re talking about includes the things that are normally not priced in the market, the environmental things that tend to get over-exploited in a market economy.

LEVITT: So let me ask you an empirical question: When we try to measure growth and the reasons why our economy has grown over the last 50 years, much of it seems to be because we’ve been more efficient. But do you think that much of that is just mismeasurement? Much of that has been degrading our natural resources and because we’re not measuring that well, we’re mistakenly thinking we’re getting better?

SOLOW: Of course, there must be mismeasurement. That’s never going to come out perfectly. But the fact that the increases in real output per person over the last 50 years or hundred years has come mainly from higher productivity rather than from extensive growth — that’s a fact. We also have very good reason to believe that the way we have done that is full — not of mismeasurements, but full of unpaid for damages to the planet, to the natural world. We still, for instance, when we measure our output, we don’t charge ourselves for the depletion of natural resources. But, of course, there are also good stories along this line. Over the last 50 years, the air quality, in this country at least, has improved, not deteriorated. So the gains in efficiency include some gains in environmental amenity. I want to avoid the word mismeasurement, Steve, because to mismeasure something suggests that you’re actually measuring a different thing from what you think you’re measuring. In our case, what we have done is decided not to measure certain things. The U.N. has a whole system of national accounts that will pay much fuller attention to the effects of human economic activity on the natural environment and the U.N. has always wanted all the major countries to adopt this. I have always laughed at myself in this respect. I believe that this full system of national accounts that the U.N. has produced would be superior to what we have now, but I am so terribly worried that if we went over to it, we would lose the possibility of having long time series to study. So I would want the lousy measurements along with the good measurements.

LEVITT: Wait, so you’re telling me that you’re in favor of our bad system of accounting, so you can keep doing your research, even at the cost of humanity’s good outcomes?

SOLOW: That’s what I laugh at myself about. Yes, I’m desperately worried. We have national accounts in the U.S. of reasonable quality going back to 1929. That is a century of national accounts. I would hate to end that, so I would be for keeping the bad numbers. Have one office in the Department of Commerce keeping the bad numbers and another department keeping the good numbers.

LEVITT: I thought you were saying you wanted to stand in the way of progress. You just want duplication of effort. That seems more reasonable.

SOLOW: Yes.

LEVITT: As long as I’ve been an economist, we economists have well recognized that our system of accounting leaves out a lot of important things. Is it surprising to you that there hasn’t been the political will to make these changes?

SOLOW: There just isn’t much interest outside of a narrow group of people that includes you and me and is therefore not terribly influential. There’s conversation about the G.D.P. all the time in the press, on T.V., and all that. And most of the people who use the phrase think that the G.D.P. is intended as a measure of economic well-being, and it is not intended as a measure of economic well-being. It’s intended as a measure of economic activity — not whether it is directed to the right goals or the right benchmarks.

LEVITT: I know you’re deeply troubled by the high and rising inequality in the United States. So what do think is driving the inequality?

SOLOW: From the beginning of the Second World War until some years after, the country was generally getting more equal. The distribution of income — and as far as we know, the distribution of wealth — were becoming more equal. Sometime in the 1970s or early eighties that changed and inequality began to worsen, inequality of income, inequality of wealth. I think that’s pretty awful. I don’t care about absolute equality. I don’t care if you make more money than I do. But the coexistence of extreme wealth and extreme poverty strikes me as immoral, to use an old-fashioned word. It’s immoral because it’s unnecessary, and it has bad consequences beyond itself. The great wealth attracts great political power and a society which tolerates extremes in equality of wealth also tolerates extreme differences in political activity and political power. I deplore that. I think it’s a blot on our society, and I have not seen any evidence or any reason to believe that we profit at all from that. So why does it happen? First of all, Steve, the answer to a question like that is almost never one thing. I think a lot of it actually is what I was already talking about. It’s the interplay between economic inequality and political inequality. You start with some economic inequality. It generates political inequality. Well, the holders of political power, the beneficiaries of that political inequality, are going to pass laws and cultivate customs that help themselves. I couldn’t put numbers on this, I couldn’t quantify it in any way, but it’s almost certainly true that some of the worsening inequality in the past 40 years or so comes from deregulation — the willingness of the political process to allow unregulated activity that once it regulated. We know where the juice behind the movement for deregulation came from. You know, the obvious example of this is the concentration of wealth in the financial services industries, and the financial services have been in the process of deregulation ever since Ronald Reagan was president. The interplay between them operating through legislation and administration is bound to be part of it.

LEVITT: Economists know how to undo inequality. It’s not a hard economic problem. It’s really a political problem.

SOLOW: I agree with that, but what I was trying to focus on is that there’s an interplay between them. It is a political problem and the political forces then push the economy in the direction of greater inequality, and that, in turn, reinforces the political inequality. You’re absolutely right to describe it as fundamentally a political problem in the sense that there would not be any substantial loss of economic efficiency if there were much less inequality.

We’ll be right back with more of my conversation with economist Robert Solow after this short break.

*      *      *

LEVITT: So you grew up in the Great Depression.

SOLOW: Yes. I was 6 years old in 1930 and I was 16-years-old in 1940. So I grew up during the whole of the Depression. Now, we were not an impoverished family. My father always had work, although he had to take jobs he didn’t like. On the other hand, from listening to my parents’ conversation, it was clear to me that the general feeling of not knowing where the next dollar is coming from, the general feeling of insecurity was the dominant thing in their conversation. That’s mostly what they talked about. One of their friends was a high school teacher of math, Mr. Ginsburg. Before the Depression, they all pitied Lou Ginsburg because he didn’t earn very much money. By the 1930s, they envied him because he had a safe and secure job. So one of the things I got out of being a Depression child was the importance of economic security. And it has made a difference because I’ve always balked at notions about the efficiency of the labor market, which amount to imposing uncertainty on workers. I think any understanding of the labor market has to take account of the fact that people really care — it’s really important to them to have a feeling of safety, of security. I still think that. It doesn’t fit so easily into standard economics textbooks, but it’s one of the things I learned from growing up in the Depression.

LEVITT: Was there a feeling, in the depths of the Great Depression, that this was it? That the market economy had failed and that this was a new normal?

SOLOW: Oh. Oh, oh, come on. Absolutely. I’d come from a generation of people whose fundamental view was that the society had failed. My experience, say, until I was 21, was of depression and war. The economy had failed the people; and the society had failed the people.

LEVITT: When the Great Recession happened in 2007 to 2009, I was struck by how fatalistic and demoralized people were. I mean, the mainstream media was fundamentally questioning whether the market economy was still a viable way to structure society. But knowing the facts — that we’d had 60 or 70 years of G.D.P. growth and that in the Great Recession, G.D.P. fell by maybe 4 percent, and unemployment peaked at 10 percent — it hardly seemed to me at the time like a justification to abandon capitalism. In the Great Depression, what, G.D.P. must have fell by 30 percent? I don’t think people today can even imagine what the Great Depression must have been like.

SOLOW: I don’t recall going back to 2007, 2009, that kind of fatalism or feeling that the system had broken down. There was much more of that in the 1930s. My whole contemporary generation, kids I knew in Brooklyn in school, an awful lot of them ended up as communists or fellow travelers or Trotskyites. And that was because they really were driven to believe that the system had broken down.

LEVITT: I’m curious, were you attracted to communism, to Trotskyism? Were you ever close to following that path?

SOLOW: No, but that’s purely accident. The most important person in my life in the 1930s was a school teacher, an English teacher. She got hold of me and taught me to read novels, serious novels, and to listen to music, and to think about things. She and her husband kind of took me in and converted me into the intellectual you see now. But now the interesting thing is that in her youth, Mrs. Touster had been the secretary to Emma Goldman, the leading American anarchist. And she thought of herself as a philosophical anarchist. Not a bomb thrower, but she believed that organized political power was a bad thing. And I acquired those ideas; and I had absolutely no interest in communism at all. To me, communism was a manifestation of organized political power and therefore a bad thing. So I went through that period of my life as a person definitely on the left, but never having the slightest inclination toward communism. I thought Trotskyites were as bad as Stalinists. Lenin was already the problem, not the solution.

LEVITT: So I’ve long had a theory that the generation of economists who grew up during the depression was the greatest generation of economists because the most talented young people, they looked around — people like you — and they could have done anything, but economic issues were the most pressing problem. And so the most talented people chose to be economists, whereas in other times, the most talented minds maybe gravitated towards physics at its heyday or engineering in the 1960s or maybe computer science later on. Do you think there’s any truth to that theory?

SOLOW: I do think that young people choosing occupations, choosing what to think about or to devote their energy to, do respond to what they see as the important problems. My contemporaries are no smarter than any other generation, but they were certainly more focused on the failures of the system and the importance of learning how to deal with the mechanics of the thing. So if the generation of economists that grew up in the Depression of the ‘30s was especially good, it wasn’t that they were especially good, it’s that they were driven by their experience to think about the right things, to worry about the right things. People like Jim Tobin and Paul Samuelson and Franco Modigliani in Europe. They’re certainly no smarter intrinsically than people today or yesterday, but their experience had focused them.

LEVITT: Now, one of the things that struck me is that your interests and your way of thinking, they’re much broader than most eminent economists.

SOLOW: What do you mean by broader?

LEVITT: Milton Friedman and Gary Becker, they seem to me to be destined from birth to be economists. Every single thing they said or did was pervaded by an economic mindset. But your worldview seems more anchored in common sense than in economics, per se. It almost seems to me like it’s an accident that you’re an economist, that you easily could have ended up being something very different. Is there any truth to that?

SOLOW: I think that’s probably true. People keep talking about, “You should learn to think like an economist.” I’m not so sure that’s a good idea. You should learn to think. Sometimes the question is economic, and the answer may be economics. But I agree with you. The Gary Becker frame of mind that children are durable goods after all, that everything can be cast in economic terms, has just never appealed to me. It doesn’t seem right. It doesn’t seem an accurate description of the way we actually think. So if in fact I’ve managed to stay away from that, I’m glad.

LEVITT: Did you know from an early age that you wanted to be an economist?

SOLOW: Oh hell no! I’ll tell you how I got to be an economist. I came home from the Army in 1945.

LEVITT: Wait, how did you end up in the army?

SOLOW: I volunteered. You want that story too?

LEVITT: Yeah, absolutely. I want all your stories.

SOLOW: That goes back to 1942. I turned 18 in 1942 and I went back to Harvard College to start my junior year. I started at age 16. So there I am in September, maybe early October, 1942, sitting in a course on the psychology of personality. It wasn’t a bad course. I was taking it because my advisor, whom I respected a lot, told me to take it. So I’m taking this course and, like the good little boy that I am, I’m busy taking notes. And all of a sudden it hit me: I can’t sit here three days a week, taking notes on the psychology of personality, when probably the most important event of my lifetime is taking place 3,000 miles away in Europe. I just can’t do that. So, I waited till the class ended, still busily taking notes. I packed up my ballpoint pen and my notebook, and I walked out the door. I walked one block to Harvard Square. I paid my nickel and got into the subway. Got out at Park Street, where I knew there was an Army recruiting office, and I joined the Army. I thought it was much more important to beat Hitler than to take notes in courses. So three years later, we’ve beaten Hitler, and in 1945, I’ve got to tell Harvard College I’m going to be back in September as a junior to finish up. So I called the college office on a telephone and they said the thing to do is to get a transcript of your freshman and sophomore year, and take it to the headquarters of your major department. So I said to my wife, “I don’t have a major department. I’ve just been screwing around taking courses, mostly in the social sciences,” And I said to her, “You majored in economics, didn’t you?” And she said, “Yes I did.” I said, “Was it interesting?” And she said, “Yes, it was.” I said, “Oh, what the hell? Let’s give it a try.”

LEVITT: And you never looked back, right? You’ve been on that trail ever since.

SOLOW: That was 1945 and that was 78 years ago. Yes.

LEVITT: So you volunteered for the Army. What was your assignment?

SOLOW: The army has a worldwide reputation for putting square pegs in round holes and vice versa. But in my case, they lit on two accidental capacities that I had. I had fairly fluent German and I knew Morse code.

LEVITT: Wait, how did you learn fluent German growing up in Brooklyn?

SOLOW: When I came to Harvard College in 1940, I was assigned, as a roommate, a German refugee, Gerhard Nellhaus, and we became fast friends, throughout his life. And I was just smart enough to say, “Hey, this is an opportunity. I’m going to take German and I’m going to be back here in the room at night and I’m going to talk German with Gerhard, and I’m going to learn German.” And so before I joined up, I had the two German courses, and I talked to Gerhard. So after those two years, I was practically fluent in German.

LEVITT: That’s pretty good, Bob. My wife is German and I’ve been trying to learn German for the last 10 years, and I’m living in Germany for a year and I can’t even understand children’s TV shows.

SOLOW: You’re too old.

LEVITT: Probably the problem.

SOLOW: But anyhow, so the Army assigned me to signal intelligence.

LEVITT: Wait, why’d you know Morse code?

SOLOW: Harvard College had a contract with the Army to find ways of teaching Morse code. And so they offered — you could come in two or three evenings a week and learn Morse code. And what the hell? I thought that might be a useful skill, so I learned Morse code. And I ended up in this unit which intercepted German radio traffic, but not big time radio traffic. Not like at Bletchley or Turing and all that. We intercepted low-level combat units. We hardly ever heard any unit larger than a battalion. And some of these messages were in code and we had to learn to break those codes in real time. But they were fairly simple codes. ‘Cause remember, the poor devils who were sending the messages were having problems too.

LEVITT: What would be an example of the simple code you had to break in real time?

SOLOW: Oh, well, the simplest things were just ciphers. Each letter of the alphabet stands for a different letter of the alphabet. But more than that, the Germans had — for these low-level combat units, they had a table of 600 different three-letter groups, and they would assign a different meaning to these three-letter groups and transmit the three-letter groups. And we had to look at a lot of traffic, occasionally find a blunder somewhere, and eventually be able to read the messages. And we did good work. We did very good work.

LEVITT: Were you right by the front lines?

SOLOW: Yes. We had to be there because these radio transmissions were very weak. And if you were any distance away, you couldn’t hear them. We worked out of two-and-a-half-ton trucks. We had to hide them because if we were seen, we could have been pulverized. And so part of our trick was to get as close to the front, to the transmitter that we’re listening to as we could get, but not be visible. And we succeeded.

LEVITT: Were you worried about dying when you were in the war?

SOLOW: From time to time, yes. But you can’t do nothing but worry. Like anybody else, I was scared sometimes. But it worked out; here I am.

You’re listening to People I (Mostly) Admire with Steve Levitt and his conversation with economist Robert Solow. After this short break, they’ll return to talk about how macroeconomics has changed over time.

*      *      *

The way economists model the macro economy has changed dramatically over the years that Robert Solow’s been studying the topic. I’m curious to hear how he feels about those changes, and also to see if he’s got any advice about growing old.

LEVITT: How do you like where macroeconomics has gotten to?

SOLOW: Well, I have to be careful here, Steve, because remember that I’m out of date. My eyesight is such that I can’t read very much anymore. So I really don’t know what the last four or five years of Chicago economics has become. But I found the advent of — D.S.G.E., dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models to be, not so much as a step backwards, but as a step out of economics. In fact, I’ve been criticized, probably justly, for making jokes about it, but it struck me as funny, as not something you could take seriously. There were times when you start reading an article in that vein, and it would start by saying, “Well, we are going to write down a ‘micro-founded model.'” It meant an economy with one person in it, and organized so that the economy carried out the wishes of that person. Well, when I was growing up and getting interested in economics, the essence of economics was that there were people and groups of people in the economy who had conflicting interests. Not only did they want different things, opposing things, they believed different things. And there’s no place for that in what passes, or what was passing a dozen years ago, for a micro-founded model. And I come back to — one of the symptoms of this is that the devotees of that kind of economics don’t play a role in discussion of what to do. If I were to ask you, “What was the Chicago position on dealing with the Covid pandemic?” I don’t think you could find anything written about that. It’s an economics that is clearly not designed to take account of the difference between people who get the disease, people who don’t get the disease, people who normally sell things that people who get the disease would have bought if they didn’t have the disease. All those things that make up the nitty gritty, they don’t pronounce on that. They have built what they think of as a brand of economics that simply has nothing to say.

LEVITT: I’ll tell you a story, Bob. After the financial crisis in 2007, there was so much criticism of economists for not predicting it. So I asked one of my senior colleagues, one of my macro colleagues, what he thought of that criticism. And he said, more or less, “Well, I think it’s stupid. It’s not our job to describe the economy. What we write down are mathematical models that try to answer difficult mathematical questions.” It was really what you’re saying, but he said it even more clearly.

SOLOW: Yes. Well, if that had been the way economics was done when I was studying the subject and learning it, I wouldn’t have done it. I would’ve found something else to do. When I first got interested in economic questions, the whole point was that the system appeared to be broken and it was necessary to find ways to patch it together. If I wanted to classify myself in schools of economics, I would like to call myself an eclectic American Keynesian. The real economy, the functioning economy out there, is full of mechanisms. There are operating characteristics that it has. You touch it here and it reacts there. You touch it there, it reacts there. And the essence was not so much to build a mathematical micro-founded model of the economy. The object was to find a couple of these mechanisms and try to understand how they operated in the imperfect world we live in. God, I do sound like an old fogie, don’t I?

LEVITT: You’re not exactly a young man. You’re 98-years-old as we speak, and I really — I use you as a model of how I’d like to grow old. It seems like you haven’t lost a step mentally. Do you think that’s just luck? Or because you’ve been so intellectually active?

SOLOW: That’s not quite right. You don’t know the reality. I’m aware of the fact that I have deteriorated physically much more than I’ve deteriorated mentally, but I was certainly sharper when I was younger than I am now. I am lucky in that I can still think. Not as well, and God knows, not as quickly. God, it takes me forever to get to the bottom of anything. But I can still think, whereas I can’t see and I can’t hear. But it’s just the luck of the draw. I don’t think there’s any good habit I had. Somewhere there’s someone, not an economist of course, who’s saying the various faculties deteriorate at different speeds and wouldn’t it be interesting to know what controls that? Maybe some enzyme, maybe some this, maybe some that, that would be a good example of the kind of research I would’ve always liked to do.

LEVITT: My father is 88-years-old, so a decade younger than you. He mentioned to me the other day that every friend he had growing up has died. But he didn’t seem too troubled by that fact. I think for him, outliving my sister, his daughter, that was far more difficult. What’s it been like for you to outlive so many of the people you’ve known?

SOLOW: I miss my friends. I miss the people in my department. We were good colleagues. I miss Paul Samuelson, a tremendous amount. I miss Cary Brown and others. It’s a lonely thing to get very old, but I’m not giving it up.

LEVITT: Are you still enjoying life?

SOLOW: On a good day certainly, or in the good parts of every day, yes. A lot of it is sort of neutral. Most days are pretty dead level. What do you expect?

LEVITT: What’s your attitude towards death? Are you afraid?

SOLOW: My attitude towards death is that an awful lot of people have managed to do it, so I guess I will too. I’m not happy at the idea. A friend of mine said, “I don’t mind dying, I just don’t want to be there when it happens.”

Talking with Robert Solow today left me with such a sense of optimism. How heartening is it that as he approaches 100 years of age, he’s still got such a spark, so much enthusiasm? I know it’s unlikely, but it at least makes me fantasize about the possibility that I’ve got another 40 years not just to live, but to thrive. I had Peter Attia on the podcast a couple of months ago, and I found his strategies for attaining an extra 10 good years of life extremely compelling. But one thing that Peter doesn’t talk much about that I’ve seen in Robert’s Solow and the small handful of other old people who’ve wowed me is how excited and curious they remain about the world around them. Now, maybe that’s partly reverse causality. When you age well it’s easier to stay engaged, but I don’t think that’s the whole story. At least I hope not. Because while it’s hard work doing the exercise and strength training Peter Attia demands, at least so far, I find there’s nothing easier than being curious about all the amazing things in the world around me. 

LEVITT: Now is the part of the show where we take a listener question and as always, I welcome Morgan, our producer, to help me out.

LEVEY: Hi, Steve. So we’ve gotten a few questions recently about the LIV Golf-PGA Tour merger and that’s because we had the head of LIV Golf, Greg Norman, on the show twice, and the second time he was on, he talked a lot about LIV Golf. So I thought this would be a good opportunity to do a little update on our guests. So starting with the LIV-PGA Tour merger, what do you think?

LEVITT: Well, it is crazy news. I don’t think anybody expected it. This is one of the most unexpected turn events I can ever imagine — that Jay Monahan, who is a commissioner of the PGA Tour, who has been demonizing the Saudis on moral ground since the beginning of LIV. Suddenly, the next thing you know, the Saudis, seem to own the PGA tour. So I don’t think anyone saw it coming.

LEVEY: So what do you think Greg Norman’s role is going to be? Just based on the press about it, it seemed like he’s really been left out of the conversation.

LEVITT: Well, when I first heard the news, I thought, “Wow, Greg Norman won. He forced the hand of the PGA tour.” But you’re right — as more details have come out, it really seems like LIV Golf is somewhat of an afterthought in this whole endeavor. Greg Norman hasn’t been mentioned very much. I think he wasn’t told that the merger was happening. It certainly seems like less of a win for Greg Norman than it did initially, but time will tell. I think we’re a long, long way from the end of this story.

LEVEY: Do you think it’ll actually go through?

LEVITT: So you know me, Morgan. My powers of prediction are terrible. I’m never right about anything, but I’ll go on the record and you can humiliate me in six months, but I’m going to say this merger will not happen.

LEVEY: Okay. Sounds good. The other guest I want to give an update on is professional quizzer Victoria Groce, because recently the World Quizzing Championships took place. Steve, do you know how Victoria did?

LEVITT: Yeah, Victoria did great. She got second place in the world. She got 170 questions correct out of 240. The winner had 171. She missed the championship by one question. But nonetheless, second in the world. That’s pretty good.

LEVEY: Well, Steve, I know that you also participated in the World Quizzing Championship. How’d you do?

LEVITT: I did compete. So after we did the episode with Victoria about a year ago, I decided that I would try to get better at trivia. And Victoria has been my unofficial coach since then and she’s put me on a regimen to try to improve. And, you know, I didn’t do great. I got 90 questions right, compared to Victoria’s 170. But it wasn’t so bad ‘cause this is a pack of pretty serious trivia nerds. So I was not unhappy with how I did.

LEVEY: How effective do you think Victoria’s training was?

LEVITT: Well, I went back after the contest and I did crunch some data. I tried to figure out: of the questions I got right, how many of them did I get right only because of the practice that Victoria put me through? And I came up with an answer of about 25, which I think is pretty impressive. I spent my whole life thinking, a little bit at least, about trivia and all of my life’s experiences only gave me 65 correct answers. And then one year of focused study gave me another 25 correct answers to get to my total of 90. So I’m getting better. So that’s for something. But let me just say, Morgan, these are hard questions and I know that trivia isn’t your thing, but there was one question that I have at inkling that you will get right. Can I try it out on you?

LEVEY: Sure.

LEVITT: Alright. Here it is: “Which word appeared in the title of a 2005 book by Steven Levitt and Stephen Dubner that explored the hidden side of many processes?”

LEVEY: “The hidden side of many processes”? I think they mean, “hidden side of everything.” Freakonomics, of course!

LEVITT: That’s right. So that question came in the middle of the contest after a string of four or five questions where I didn’t even know what they were talking about, so it definitely buoyed my spirits to hear my own name called out as one of the questions.

LEVEY: If you have a question for us, our email is pima@freakonomics.com. That’s P-I-M-A@freakonomics.com. We read every email that’s sent and we look forward to reading yours. I’d also like to correct the record and say that my friends and I used to go to a regular pub trivia night and we would win every week. So I’m not sure that “trivia’s not my thing,” Levitt.

LEVITT: Okay. Next year, Morgan, you and me, World Quizzing Championship, we’ll try to, combined, add up to Victoria’s score.

LEVEY: Sounds like a still lofty goal for us.

LEVITT: Yeah, it is.

In two weeks we’ll be back with a brand-new episode featuring David Simon. He’s the creator of the TV show The Wire and he’s also a key player in the ongoing Hollywood writers strike.

SIMON: We are the sainted and anointed emissaries of honest labor. And these sons of bitches are just greed heads.

As always, thanks for listening and we’ll see you soon.

*      *      *

People I (Mostly) Admire is part of the Freakonomics Radio Network, which also includes Freakonomics Radio, No Stupid Questions, and The Economics of Everyday Things. All our shows are produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio. This episode was produced by Morgan Levey with help from Lyric Bowditch, and mixed by Jasmin Klinger. Our theme music was composed by Luis Guerra. To listen ad-free, subscribe to Stitcher Premium. We can be reached at pima@freakonomics.com, that’s P-I-M-A@freakonomics.com. Thanks for listening.

SOLOW: You’re speeding up. Remember, you’re talking to someone who’s going to be 99 in four months; the brain works slowly.

LEVITT: Ok!

Read full Transcript

Sources

  • Robert Solow, professor emeritus of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Resources

Extras

Episode Video

Comments